Greece
It
now seems inevitable that Greece will default on its debts, with all
sorts of disastrous scenarios being discussed, particularly if it has to
leave the euro.
But I know from my experience of working with Jubilee 2000 to
"drop the debt" of poor countries in Africa and Latin America that
there is life and economic recovery after sovereign debt crises.
Countries that defaulted in the 1990s suffered recessions that lasted briefly. Then came the rebound, as Arvind Subramanian of the Petersen Institute shows. Argentina grew by 8% after its default, Russia by more than 7%, and Indonesia by 5% after its crisis.
Of course Greece would initially suffer a severe shock and
economic contraction. Its elites would intensify the export of their
wealth to, for example, the City of London, causing inflation.
Greece would have to issue an alternative, parallel currency -
at a large discount to the euro - to finance domestic economic
activity.
But Greek exporters would benefit from a mega-devaluation of
this new currency, and increased competitiveness vis-a-vis European
partners, especially Germany.
There are other upsides for Greece too. To understand why, we
need to recognise that the eurozone monetary framework is like a
"golden corset". By defaulting on its debts, Greece can escape the
"corset" that resembles the "barbaric relic" that Keynes deemed the Gold
Standard of the 1930s.
The eurozone's "constitution" denies member countries like Greece a proper functioning central bank and monetary system.
The Greek government does not have access to a central bank
which, like the Bank of England (BoE), generates finance (quantitative
easing or "liquidity") for both the private banking system, but also
government.
The BoE has effectively financed the UK government's deficit by
creating new money digitally, and then buying up government bonds or
gilts.
Instead the eurozone framework - articles 123-5 of the Lisbon
Treaty and European Central Bank (ECB) statutes - forces poor countries
like Greece to turn to the private banking sector, the international
bond markets, for finance.
Greece is a poor country. The government of Greece needs
money, has a poor tax-collection record and, as a member of the euro,
repays loans in what is effectively a foreign currency.
Despite these problems, and by "cooking the books", Greek
politicians persuaded the EU to admit Greece to the euro - to gain
access to easy but ultimately dear money.
Like the Northern Rock borrower
persuaded to take out a dodgy loan worth 125% of their property's value,
Greece was lured into a trap.
But neither Greece nor the Northern Rock sub-prime borrowers
were simply victims. They weren't just pushed into borrowing. They were
also pulled.
Big, private financial institutions were facing bankruptcy,
and needed to lend risky loans to generate higher returns and avoid
insolvency.
By 2001, when Greece joined the euro, the globalised
financial system was already facing the threat of insolvency and
systemic collapse. After a series of financial crises in Asia, and the
Russian default of 1998, the dotcom asset bubble exploded in 2001,
precipitating a near-death experience for both Wall Street and the City
of London.
Bankers perched precariously on an unstable global Ponzi
scheme, and needed to earn higher returns fast to balance losses
elsewhere - and avoid systemic failure.
Sub-prime borrowers were quick, risky, but easy targets that paid higher rates of interest, generating higher returns.
Rates on loans (bonds) to countries like Greece, Portugal and
Ireland were lower, but risky bonds were guaranteed by EU taxpayers and
the ECB. This offered private bankers precisely the guarantees and
liquidity needed to shore up losses and fund speculation elsewhere.
But taxpayer-backed compensation
to bankers in the event of default required enormous sacrifices by the
Greek people and the handover of their public assets to creditors.
On 20 June 2011, the acting head of the IMF, representing
creditors, called for "immediate and far-reaching structural reforms,
privatisation, and the opening of [Greece's] markets to foreign
ownership and competition".
The good news is that poor Greece can default, defy the IMF and private bankers and escape from this debt trap.
It can cling to precious public assets. It can stop propping
up a global banking system that dodges the discipline of free-market
forces and hides behind the skirts of taxpayer-backed institutions like
the ECB and IMF.
And it can do this without exiting from the eurozone. Just as
I do not have to leave sterling if I default on my loan to you, so
Greece does not have to leave the euro if it defaults on loans to
private bankers.
So Greece will show the world not only that there is an alternative, but that the alternative could be very good.
No comments:
Post a Comment